Battle of the Systems: Why Economic Renewal Needs Joined-up Thinking - RSA

Battle of the Systems: Why Economic Renewal Needs Joined-up Thinking

Blog 6 Comments

  • Picture of
  • Economics and Finance
  • Fellowship
  • Social mobility

In the first of a two part blog series, Martin Whitlock FRSA discusses why socially progressive economic policy is systematically rejected in the UK.

Many people think that the UK's economic model is broken, and many are promoting policy proposals that will help to fix it. 

With housing unaffordable, there is growing support for schemes that de-couple the price of a home from the asset value of the land it sits on

With a boom in low paid, insecure work, and a benefits system that leaves many in poverty, there is unprecedented interest in UBI, a universal basic income

With a banking system that inflates asset values and promotes consumer debt while starving the real economy of investment, there is a flourishing movement in favour of sovereign money

And with rising levels of illness, overwork, loneliness, and environmental degradation, there is an increasing focus on wellbeing, both as an outcome and a measure for a healthy economic system. 

In addition we have movements for fair trade, social enterprise, revival of the commons, land value tax, the Robin Hood tax, degrowth and many others. Each movement, each campaign, has its preferred policy solution, each designed to make the economy more productive of real value. 

In the terms of a recent RSA research paper, these are all examples of design thinking. They are well thought-out ideas, each of which could make a real difference. The problem is that the system rejects them, through a mechanism that the paper calls a “system immune response”. The effectiveness of great design, the paper argues, is blunted by a lack of “systems thinking”, which means understanding what has to happen for the system to accept a proposed innovation. 

In addressing this problem it's worth noting that this immunity is adaptive, not innate. Adaptive immunity is where the system decides to trigger an immune response to something it does not like. It is not obliged to make that decision, and it did not always do so. 

Forty years ago, the UK had seven million socially-provided homes at affordable rents, and strict controls over rents and tenure in the private sector. Banks gambled with their own rather than the public's money and were cautious for that reason. Mortgages mostly came from mutual societies that matched people's savings to borrowings in a risk-free way. Governments wielded a range of macro-economic tools including exchange controls and the setting of interest rates. Aspects of a sort of de facto UBI were evident in social policy, with free further and higher education supported by maintenance grants, and a benefits system that encouraged people to find work that suited their experience and qualifications. 

Between 1979 and 2007, all this changed. The post-war consensus, that the enhancement of social welfare was a key objective of economic policy, was superseded by a weakly regulated, low-tax, supply-side approach favouring the interests of the owners of capital, characterised as “trickle-down” economics. Over time, a new consensus formed around this approach, which acquired the name of neo-liberalism. 

Neo-liberalism assumes that money, rather than being a tool to facilitate its creation, is a comprehensive proxy for wealth itself, and that policy should seek to maximise the quantity of money wealth by adopting free market rather than socially interventionist policies. Housing has been the poster boy for this theory: 40% of former council homes are now owned by private landlords, rents are uncontrolled and there is no security of tenure. Prices have risen from less than four times average household annual earnings to nearly eight times. Housing in the past 40 years has created a huge amount of wealth when measured purely in money terms, 

Although money has always been associated with private wealth, the idea that the public realm could be valued in this way was a genuine innovation. Prior to the 1980s the state was guardian to a vast portfolio of assets, the perceived value of which lay not in monetary equivalence but in their social contribution. Housing, libraries, parks, sports facilities, utilities, communication networks and a comprehensive public education system all had their origins in the state philanthropy that developed in the Victorian era. More recently the NHS was born out of the same spirit, while transport systems and key industries were adopted by the public realm. The output sought from these assets in policy terms was not a cash return but an improvement to the quality of people's lives. 

Neo-liberal theory rejected state philanthropy in favour of monetising public assets, returning the cash to people to spend in newly created commercial markets. A combination of tax cuts - fuelled by asset sales and the proceeds of North Sea oil - and the tide of “free money” generated by demutualisations, the instant profits made on shares in newly privatised companies and the discounted sale of public housing all gave credence to the neo-liberal principle that money is king.

This explains the “system immune response” to ideas rooted in principles of fairness or the collective good. Unlike socially productive assets (such as the NHS or the road system) which find their value in a shared need, money is an expression of personal ownership. In a highly monetised economy, considerations of property rights and entitlement consume all others. 

As David Cameron discovered with his “big society”, when you parachute social programmes into a system of which the principal driver is personal profit, the system works to co-opt, subvert or exploit them. Many are the public/private partnerships that have ended in tears for this reason. 

Housing is a case in point. Local authorities tasked with providing affordable housing must also leverage their assets for maximum financial gain. Thus, residential sites in the public realm are sold to developers with only a proportion of the proceeds reinvested in affordable homes. By feeding the commercial market in this way, authorities lose control of their housing assets and increase the scale of the affordable housing problem they are trying to solve. 

Proposals for a UBI are similarly vulnerable in an economy designed to capture people's cash or oblige them to borrow it. Much of the additional money may well be absorbed by higher rent and mortgage payments. This, after all, is what happened when hundreds of billions of pounds were injected into the economy through the policy of quantitative easing. The preference of commercial banks to lend against appreciating assets inflated the property bubble and starved the productive economy of investment. 

That the independent Bank of England showered the banks with this largesse, rather than directing it at productive investment, public services or affordable housing, shows the scale of the challenge faced by the campaign for sovereign money in a neo-liberal environment. In a system in which capital flows freely, changing the way that money is created will not be allowed to compromise the conditions that attract foreign capital to support the UK's lopsided balance of payments. 

For the same reason, the likelihood that a UK government will cease to prioritise money growth in favour of human and environmental wellbeing is slim in the extreme. GDP is a terrible measure of the things that people really value in their lives, but while it remains the measure that the money markets judge discussion of the numerous proposed alternatives will continue to be marginalised in political discourse. 

By monetising every aspect of the national economy, neo-liberalism has created an environment in which socially progressive economic policy is systematically rejected. Despite this, however, change is possible. In a further post I will discuss what is needed to bring it about. 

Join the discussion

6 Comments

Please login to post a comment or reply

Don't have an account? Click here to register.

  • The potential for radical change certainly exists with surveys suggesting for example that half of all UK voters would already support a Basic Income, which begs the question why mainstream political parties aren't adopting these policies faster?


    http://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/home-news/universal-basic-income-benefits-unemployment-a7939551.html


    As you suggest a key problem is that although many of the new policy ideas we need to adopt are already well understood, we still lack a simple narrative that ties them into a compelling vision for the future.  Within my lifetime there have only been two big narrative stories, which are still closely linked to the history of the two major parties. Both of these models are clearly not fit for purpose in the 20th century:


    The Keynesian model has been the core of labour party policy since the 1940's.  Tony Blair tempered this with elements of neo-liberalism during the New Labour era, but Corbyn seems set to restore its central position.  However, Keynes original model can no longer work in a Global economy.  For one thing it regulated international trade with fixed exchange-rates and capital controls which have long since gone, and are unlikely to return again.  But more importantly a key plank of the Keynesian model was the goal of full employment, which gave unions the power to push up wages and working conditions over time.  But full employment in well paid full-time roles is disappearing rapidly through automation, leaving workers with no bargaining power in an increasingly crowded jobs market.


    The neo-liberal model has been the core of Conservative policy since 1979 and has repeatedly been used to justify cuts in welfare and public services, combined with deregulation and reduced taxation of private enterprise.  Despite the long-term failure of trickle-down economics, and the spectacular banking crisis of 2007/08, conservative thinking has still not advanced from this Thatcherite base, leaving them even more stuck in the past than Labour.


    The problem is that no-one has yet been able to formulate a simple new narrative about inclusive and sustainable economic growth.  This new narrative must not only speak effectively to those "left-behind" by the neo-liberal economy, but also unite voters from both sides of the political divide. Our future debate must no longer be defined in terms of left or right, but between those stuck in failing models of the past (Keynesian/Neo-Liberal), and the progressive ideas that we now need in a highly automated Global economy.  The first party (old or new) to achieve this, will be in a strong position to win voter support for a new and progressive agenda that is now desperately needed.


    Robert P Bruce

    author www.TheGlobalRace.net 


      

  • That may be part of it, but the severe cuts in staffing in public services has left them trying to run the old systems without the capacity to do so. Re Local government it is the middle to lower tier that has gone. The higher up management are making decisions without the research and information that the lower management would do and hence miss things that would have been flagged up. So new ideas of doing things has no one there to work in collaboration. The methods of working are stuck in the past because they don't have the capacity to innovate. It is noticeable looking at other countries and grassroots initiatives how much freer people are to innovate. Monetising is a problem but control of almost every aspect by Central government is much more of a problem despite the so called devolved areas and city mayors.     

    • This is a very good point, but actually I think the over-monetisation of the economy and the losses we have experienced to the more productive service-oriented tiers of local (and national) government are two aspects of the same problem. For so long as we consider public services to be a cost to society (because they "cost" money) rather than a benefit to society on account of the life-enhancing value they provide, they will always be vulnerable to cuts, justified as a response to "market forces" which are driven by money-value.

      A rational economy would value services according to the social good that flows from them. As I argue in Part 2 of this post, we're not likely to achieve an economy that works for wellbeing and the common good without a systemic approach, which includes challenging the flawed assumption that money represents real wealth and productive value.

  • Well made points.

    I, with another RSA member, am involved with an open source project to develop a public consensus around the purpose of society - refuting the political class inspired Neo-Liberal narrative in favour of a more inclusive, representative desire.

    I would love you to get involved in helping to drive this initiative to, borrowing your language, reprogram the systemic immune response.

    • Many thanks. Sounds like an interesting project. I'd love to have further details. Maybe send me a message via MyRSA (click on my name on the right to go to the contact page).


      Meanwhile, if you have a moment, Part 2 of my blog is now out at: https://www.thersa.org/discover/publications-and-articles/rsa-blogs/2017/11/battle-of-the-systems-2-how-change-can-come-quickly-if-we-want-it-to